Most Popular
1. It’s a New Macro, the Gold Market Knows It, But Dead Men Walking Do Not (yet)- Gary_Tanashian
2.Stock Market Presidential Election Cycle Seasonal Trend Analysis - Nadeem_Walayat
3. Bitcoin S&P Pattern - Nadeem_Walayat
4.Nvidia Blow Off Top - Flying High like the Phoenix too Close to the Sun - Nadeem_Walayat
4.U.S. financial market’s “Weimar phase” impact to your fiat and digital assets - Raymond_Matison
5. How to Profit from the Global Warming ClImate Change Mega Death Trend - Part1 - Nadeem_Walayat
7.Bitcoin Gravy Train Trend Forecast 2024 - - Nadeem_Walayat
8.The Bond Trade and Interest Rates - Nadeem_Walayat
9.It’s Easy to Scream Stocks Bubble! - Stephen_McBride
10.Fed’s Next Intertest Rate Move might not align with popular consensus - Richard_Mills
Last 7 days
S&P Stock Market Trend Forecast to Dec 2024 - 16th Apr 24
No Deposit Bonuses: Boost Your Finances - 16th Apr 24
Global Warming ClImate Change Mega Death Trend - 8th Apr 24
Gold Is Rallying Again, But Silver Could Get REALLY Interesting - 8th Apr 24
Media Elite Belittle Inflation Struggles of Ordinary Americans - 8th Apr 24
Profit from the Roaring AI 2020's Tech Stocks Economic Boom - 8th Apr 24
Stock Market Election Year Five Nights at Freddy's - 7th Apr 24
It’s a New Macro, the Gold Market Knows It, But Dead Men Walking Do Not (yet)- 7th Apr 24
AI Revolution and NVDA: Why Tough Going May Be Ahead - 7th Apr 24
Hidden cost of US homeownership just saw its biggest spike in 5 years - 7th Apr 24
What Happens To Gold Price If The Fed Doesn’t Cut Rates? - 7th Apr 24
The Fed is becoming increasingly divided on interest rates - 7th Apr 24
The Evils of Paper Money Have no End - 7th Apr 24
Stock Market Presidential Election Cycle Seasonal Trend Analysis - 3rd Apr 24
Stock Market Presidential Election Cycle Seasonal Trend - 2nd Apr 24
Dow Stock Market Annual Percent Change Analysis 2024 - 2nd Apr 24
Bitcoin S&P Pattern - 31st Mar 24
S&P Stock Market Correlating Seasonal Swings - 31st Mar 24
S&P SEASONAL ANALYSIS - 31st Mar 24
Here's a Dirty Little Secret: Federal Reserve Monetary Policy Is Still Loose - 31st Mar 24
Tandem Chairman Paul Pester on Fintech, AI, and the Future of Banking in the UK - 31st Mar 24
Stock Market Volatility (VIX) - 25th Mar 24
Stock Market Investor Sentiment - 25th Mar 24
The Federal Reserve Didn't Do Anything But It Had Plenty to Say - 25th Mar 24

Market Oracle FREE Newsletter

How to Protect your Wealth by Investing in AI Tech Stocks

QE2, They Just Don't Get It

Interest-Rates / Quantitative Easing Nov 12, 2010 - 12:37 PM GMT

By: Paul_L_Kasriel

Interest-Rates

Best Financial Markets Analysis ArticleNo, I am not talking about the Democratic Party. I am talking about the mainstream commentators on the Federal Reserve's second round of quantitative easing, or QE2. In their defense, perhaps one of the reasons they don't get is because the way the Fed, itself, marketed it. This might suggest that the Fed doesn't really get it either. Firstly, the fact that the Fed announced that QE2 would involve the purchase of Treasury coupon securities rather than Treasury bills implied that one of the goals of QE2 was to bring down the interest rate levels on longer-maturity securities. Why is it so desirable to bring down the yield on longer-maturity securities? Because for decades, economists have clung to the unsubstantiated hypothesis that the interest rates on longer-maturity securities are what "count" in terms of decisions related to private-fixed investment expenditures.


These economists believe that lower interest rates on longer-maturity securities promote private fixed-investment expenditures. These same economists failed to observe that the interest rates on longer-maturity securities behave pro-cyclically. That is, these rates rise when credit demand and spending growth are rising and fall during recessions. One of the most, but far from perfect, leading indicators is the spread between the yield on the Treasury 10-year security and the rate on federal funds. Typically, but again, not always, this yield spread is positively correlated with real GDP growth (see Chart 1). Because the yields on the 10-year and 30-year Treasury securities have been rising since early October (see Chart 2), when QE2 fever took hold in the financial markets, the chorus has started that QE2 will fail. Had the Fed said that QE2 would involve the purchase of $600 billion of Treasury bills rather than Treasury coupon securities, we could have avoided at this phase of uninformed criticism of the policy. Of course, the chorus of critics would have complained that by the Fed purchasing bills rather than coupons it was not affecting the "important" part of the yield curve.

Another Fed rationalization for embarking on QE2 was to raise inflation expectations. Why in the world would an independent central bank want to raise inflation expectations? Isn't the whole idea of central bank independence to contain inflation? Well, again, economists are hung up on the "real" rate of interest - that is, the observable nominal interest rate minus the unobservable investor inflation expectations. That real rates of interest influence economic decisions has a lot more theoretical basis than does the notion that nominal bond yields do. But even though there is more theoretical underpinning for real rates than nominal rates, there is little empirical support. After all, if real interest rates were such a good predictor of future economic activity, why is there not a real interest rate in the Conference Board's index of Leading Economic Indicators?

The folks who put this index together are guided by what "works," not by theoretical purity. One reason that I believe that the empirical support for a real rate of interest as a leading indicator is lacking, aside from difficulties in directly measuring inflation expectations, is that equilibrium real rate of interest is always changing, just as the equilibrium price of copper changes from day to day due to changes in supply and demand. When the levels of interest rates are low and especially when the levels of short-maturity interest rates are approaching zero, which they are now, because nominal interest rates cannot move into negative territory, the only way to get real interest rates lower is to raise investors' inflation expectations.

The Fed appears to have made some progress in this area even before purchasing its first security of the $600 billion tranche. In recent weeks, the yield on the Treasury Inflation-Protected 5-year security has moved into negative territory and the yield on the Treasury Inflation-Protected 10-year security has fallen (see Chart 3). The yields on these inflation-protected securities are proxies for real interest rates. So, if lower real interest rates are the goal of QE2, then "mission accomplished."


But I do not believe that bringing down nominal interest rates, real interest rates, the foreign-exchange value of the dollar and/or raising the value of U.S. equities is what QE2 is, or should be about. I think that if the Fed desires a quicker pace of nominal GDP growth, the goal of QE2 should be to increase the quantity of the sum of Federal Reserve and commercial banking system credit. After all, why is it called quantitative easing if it does not involve quantities? The Federal Reserve has the unique ability to be able to create credit figuratively "out of thin air." So does the commercial banking system, if the Fed provides the "seed money." The ability to create credit out of thin air implies that the recipients of that credit can increase their current spending without any other entity in the economy having to cut back on its current spending. Chart 4 shows that combined Federal Reserve and commercial banking system credit have recently contracted at an unprecedented rate. The rate of contraction is slowing. The goal of QE2 should be to get this credit aggregate growing. If $600 billion of securities purchases by the Fed does not result in growth in this credit aggregate, then the Fed could increase the quantity of its securities purchases. Milton Friedman passed away only a short time ago, in 2006. It seems that much of his wisdom about the importance of quantities rather than prices (that is, interest rates) with regard to monetary policy passed with him.


Paul Kasriel is the recipient of the 2006 Lawrence R. Klein Award for Blue Chip Forecasting Accuracy

by Paul Kasriel
The Northern Trust Company
Economic Research Department - Daily Global Commentary

Copyright © 2010 Paul Kasriel
Paul joined the economic research unit of The Northern Trust Company in 1986 as Vice President and Economist, being named Senior Vice President and Director of Economic Research in 2000. His economic and interest rate forecasts are used both internally and by clients. The accuracy of the Economic Research Department's forecasts has consistently been highly-ranked in the Blue Chip survey of about 50 forecasters over the years. To that point, Paul received the prestigious 2006 Lawrence R. Klein Award for having the most accurate economic forecast among the Blue Chip survey participants for the years 2002 through 2005.

The opinions expressed herein are those of the author and do not necessarily represent the views of The Northern Trust Company. The Northern Trust Company does not warrant the accuracy or completeness of information contained herein, such information is subject to change and is not intended to influence your investment decisions.

Paul L. Kasriel Archive

© 2005-2022 http://www.MarketOracle.co.uk - The Market Oracle is a FREE Daily Financial Markets Analysis & Forecasting online publication.


Post Comment

Only logged in users are allowed to post comments. Register/ Log in